347 research outputs found

    Zipf's Law for Atlas Models

    Full text link
    A set of data with positive values follows a Pareto distribution if the log-log plot of value versus rank is approximately a straight line. A Pareto distribution satisfies Zipf's law if the log-log plot has a slope of -1. Since many types of ranked data follow Zipf's law, it is considered a form of universality. We propose a mathematical explanation for this phenomenon based on Atlas models and first-order models, systems of positive continuous semimartingales with parameters that depend only on rank. We show that the stable distribution of an Atlas model will follow Zipf's law if and only if two natural conditions, conservation and completeness, are satisfied. Since Atlas models and first-order models can be constructed to approximate systems of time-dependent rank-based data, our results can explain the universality of Zipf's law for such systems. However, ranked data generated by other means may follow non-Zipfian Pareto distributions. Hence, our results explain why Zipf's law holds for word frequency, firm size, household wealth, and city size, while it does not hold for earthquake magnitude, cumulative book sales, the intensity of solar flares, and the intensity of wars, all of which follow non-Zipfian Pareto distributions.Comment: Accepted for publication by the Applied Probability Trust (http://www.appliedprobability.org) in the Journal of Applied Probability 57.4 (December 2020

    A Rank-Based Approach to Zipf's Law

    Full text link
    An Atlas model is a rank-based system of continuous semimartingales for which the steady-state values of the processes follow a power law, or Pareto distribution. For a power law, the log-log plot of these steady-state values versus rank is a straight line. Zipf's law is a power law for which the slope of this line is -1. In this note, rank-based conditions are found under which an Atlas model will follow Zipf's law. An advantage of this rank-based approach is that it provides information about the dynamics of systems that result in Zipf's law.Comment: 6 page

    Empirical Methods for Dynamic Power Law Distributions in the Social Sciences

    Full text link
    This paper introduces nonparametric econometric methods that characterize general power law distributions under basic stability conditions. These methods extend the literature on power laws in the social sciences in several directions. First, we show that any stationary distribution in a random growth setting is shaped entirely by two factors - the idiosyncratic volatilities and reversion rates (a measure of cross-sectional mean reversion) for different ranks in the distribution. This result is valid regardless of how growth rates and volatilities vary across different economic agents, and hence applies to Gibrat's law and its extensions. Second, we present techniques to estimate these two factors using panel data. Third, we show how our results offer a structural explanation for a generalized size effect in which higher-ranked processes grow more slowly than lower-ranked processes on average. Finally, we employ our empirical methods using panel data on commodity prices and show that our techniques accurately describe the empirical distribution of relative commodity prices. We also show the existence of a generalized "size" effect for commodities, as predicted by our econometric theory.Comment: 33 pages, 7 figures. arXiv admin note: text overlap with arXiv:1601.0409

    Adiabatic potentials using multiple radio frequencies

    Full text link
    Adiabatic radio frequency (RF) potentials are powerful tools for creating advanced trapping geometries for ultra-cold atoms. While the basic theory of RF trapping is well understood, studies of more complicated setups involving multiple resonant frequencies in the limit where their effects cannot be treated independently are rare. Here we present an approach based on Floquet theory and show that it offers significant corrections to existing models when two RF frequencies are near degenerate. Furthermore it has no restrictions on the dimension, the number of frequencies or the orientation of the RF fields. We show that the added degrees of freedom can, for example, be used to create a potential that allows for easy creation of ring vortex solitons.Comment: 9 Pages, 6 Figure

    Permutation-Weighted Portfolios and the Efficiency of Commodity Futures Markets

    Full text link
    A market portfolio is a portfolio in which each asset is held at a weight proportional to its market value. Functionally generated portfolios are portfolios for which the logarithmic return relative to the market portfolio can be decomposed into a function of the market weights and a process of locally finite variation, and this decomposition is convenient for characterizing the long-term behavior of the portfolio. A permutation-weighted portfolio is a portfolio in which the assets are held at weights proportional to a permutation of their market values, and such a portfolio is functionally generated only for markets with two assets (except for the identity permutation). A reverse-weighted portfolio is a portfolio in which the asset with the greatest market weight is assigned the smallest market weight, the asset with the second-largest weight is assigned the second-smallest, and so forth. Although the reverse-weighted portfolio in a market with four or more assets is not functionally generated, it is still possible to characterize its long-term behavior using rank-based methods. This result is applied to a market of commodity futures, where we show that the reverse price-weighted portfolio substantially outperforms the price-weighted portfolio from 1977-2018.Comment: 18 pages, 8 figures, 2 table

    Asset Price Distributions and Efficient Markets

    Full text link
    We explore a decomposition in which returns on a large class of portfolios relative to the market depend on a smooth non-negative drift and changes in the asset price distribution. This decomposition is obtained using general continuous semimartingale price representations, and is thus consistent with virtually any asset pricing model. Fluctuations in portfolio relative returns depend on stochastic time-varying dispersion in asset prices. Thus, our framework uncovers an asset pricing factor whose existence emerges from an accounting identity universal across different economic and financial environments, a fact that has deep implications for market efficiency. In particular, in a closed, dividend-free market in which asset price dispersion is relatively constant, a large class of portfolios must necessarily outperform the market portfolio over time. We show that price dispersion in commodity futures markets has increased only slightly, and confirm the existence of substantial excess returns that co-vary with changes in price dispersion as predicted by our theory.Comment: 45 pages, 6 figures, 3 table

    The Rank Effect for Commodities

    Full text link
    We uncover a large and significant low-minus-high rank effect for commodities across two centuries. There is nothing anomalous about this anomaly, nor is it clear how it can be arbitraged away. Using nonparametric econometric methods, we demonstrate that such a rank effect is a necessary consequence of a stationary relative asset price distribution. We confirm this prediction using daily commodity futures prices and show that a portfolio consisting of lower-ranked, lower-priced commodities yields 23% higher annual returns than a portfolio consisting of higher-ranked, higher-priced commodities. These excess returns have a Sharpe ratio nearly twice as high as the U.S. stock market yet are uncorrelated with market risk. In contrast to the extensive literature on asset pricing factors and anomalies, our results are structural and rely on minimal and realistic assumptions for the long-run behavior of relative asset prices.Comment: 25 pages, 10 figures, 1 tabl

    A Statistical Model of Inequality

    Full text link
    This paper develops a nonparametric statistical model of wealth distribution that imposes little structure on the fluctuations of household wealth. In this setting, we use new techniques to obtain a closed-form household-by-household characterization of the stable distribution of wealth and show that this distribution is shaped entirely by two factors - the reversion rates (a measure of cross-sectional mean reversion) and idiosyncratic volatilities of wealth across different ranked households. By estimating these factors, our model can exactly match the U.S. wealth distribution. This provides information about the current trajectory of inequality as well as estimates of the distributional effects of progressive capital taxes. We find evidence that the U.S. wealth distribution might be on a temporarily unstable trajectory, thus suggesting that further increases in top wealth shares are likely in the near future. For capital taxes, we find that a small tax levied on just 1% of households substantially reshapes the distribution of wealth and reduces inequality.Comment: 46 pages, 9 tables, 8 figure

    The Rank Effect

    Full text link
    We decompose returns for portfolios of bottom-ranked, lower-priced assets relative to the market into rank crossovers and changes in the relative price of those bottom-ranked assets. This decomposition is general and consistent with virtually any asset pricing model. Crossovers measure changes in rank and are smoothly increasing over time, while return fluctuations are driven by volatile relative price changes. Our results imply that in a closed, dividend-free market in which the relative price of bottom-ranked assets is approximately constant, a portfolio of those bottom-ranked assets will outperform the market portfolio over time. We show that bottom-ranked relative commodity futures prices have increased only slightly, and confirm the existence of substantial excess returns predicted by our theory. If these excess returns did not exist, then top-ranked relative prices would have had to be much higher in 2018 than those actually observed -- this would imply a radically different commodity price distribution.Comment: 47 pages, 10 figures, 5 tables. arXiv admin note: substantial text overlap with arXiv:1810.1284

    Exciton dynamics in emergent Rydberg lattices

    Full text link
    The dynamics of excitons in a one-dimensional ensemble with partial spatial order are studied. During optical excitation, cold Rydberg atoms spontaneously organize into regular spatial arrangements due to their mutual interactions. This emergent lattice is used as the starting point to study resonant energy transfer triggered by driving a nSnS to n′Pn^\prime P transition using a microwave field. The dynamics are probed by detecting the survival probability of atoms in the nSnS Rydberg state. Experimental data qualitatively agree with our theoretical predictions including the mapping onto XXZ spin model in the strong-driving limit. Our results suggest that emergent Rydberg lattices provide an ideal platform to study coherent energy transfer in structured media without the need for externally imposed potentials
    • …
    corecore